In his recent book The Price of Inequality, Joseph Stiglitz
condemns America for its “1 percent problem”. For the past thirty years, the
nation has become increasingly divided; the upper class has seen the rapid
growth in their income while the lower class has lagged behind. This gap in
wealth has expanded so dramatically that by 2007, “the average after-tax income
of the top 1 percent had reached $1.3 million, but that of the bottom 20
percent amounted to only $17,800” (Stiglitz, 5).
Unequal distribution of wealth has
always existed in our society. In the past, the relatively higher incomes of
the wealthy were justified on the basis of marginal
productivity theory. According to the theory, the wealthy owned “a scarce
and valuable skill, the market will reward [them] amply, because of [their] contribution
to output” (37). However, there is no
compelling evidence that the productivity of the top 1 percent have increased
so significantly over time as to justify their outsized bonuses while the
average wage for typical laborers has stagnated.
Evidently, the unequal distribution
of wealth today requires a new explanation. Stiglitz accuses the failure of
market as the main contributor of inequality. A shrewd economist, he
acknowledges that the free market capitalism does not always work perfectly.
There are negative externalities, imperfect information, and agency problems that
cause the market to fail. Stiglitz argues that these distortions of market
occur because private incentives and social returns are not in alignment (42).
In other words, the private interest of a corporation does not necessarily reflect
what is good for society as a whole.
Stiglitz argues that it is the
responsibility of government to design policies—taxes and regulations—that make
these discrete interests align. However, the top 1 percent has successfully
manipulated the political system to favor the persistence of inequality by
lobbying, threatening to outsource jobs, and electing the like-minded political
representatives to power. As a result, there have been many policies that favor
the wealthy such as regressive tax, bank deregulation, and lax corporate
governance. Such laws have diminished opportunities for the poor and
perpetuated the rent seeking behavior among the top 1 percent.
One might wonder whether Stiglitz is advocating for minimum government intervention since the wealthy have actively utilized policies to their advantage. Quite contrary, Stiglitz asserts there should be a stronger government that can curb the influence of top 1 percent and create a more competitive economy. He strongly believes that greater equality can lead to a sustainable long-term economic growth as it was when “America grew together—with growth in income in every segment” for thirty years after WWII (5). Furthermore, greater equality can induce trust among different social sectors and thus save our ‘democracy in peril’ (153).
One might wonder whether Stiglitz is advocating for minimum government intervention since the wealthy have actively utilized policies to their advantage. Quite contrary, Stiglitz asserts there should be a stronger government that can curb the influence of top 1 percent and create a more competitive economy. He strongly believes that greater equality can lead to a sustainable long-term economic growth as it was when “America grew together—with growth in income in every segment” for thirty years after WWII (5). Furthermore, greater equality can induce trust among different social sectors and thus save our ‘democracy in peril’ (153).
In Stiglitz’s view, inequality is
problematic because it begets instability. The 2007—2008 Financial Crisis not
only revealed the magnitude of inequality but also aggravated it. By transferring
money from the bottom up to top, inequality reduced total demand in the economy
and therefore increased unemployment (106). Amidst the economic instability, banks
engaged in predatory lending, in
which they made too many reckless loans. When the housing bubble bursted, the
wealth of the bottom and the middle evaporated with the value of their homes.
On the other hand, the top 1 percent only lost part of their wealth thanks to the
massive government bail out and the Fed’s prompt action to lower interest
rates. In fact, their recovery from the crisis
was so successful that “the wealthiest 1 percent...had 225 times the wealth of
the typical American, almost double the ratio in 1962 or 1983” (10). In the
end, the financial crisis that resulted from the pervasive inequality eventually
further deepened it.
What seems particularly interesting to
me about this interpretation of the recent financial crisis is Stiglitz’s overly
sympathetic attitude toward the borrowers. While he acknowledges that people
did spend far more money than they could afford, Stiglitz seems to only portray
them as victims. He asserts that many banks took advantage of the “least
educated and financially unsophisticated in our society...[by] selling them
costly mortgages and hiding details of the fees” (240). Undoubtedly, the US
financial system prior to the crisis played an important role in encouraging
such excessive consumptions. However, I believe that borrowers also share some
responsibility in triggering the recession by underestimating the risk of their
investment and poorly budgeting.
In the last chapter, Stiglitz sets out a reform agenda in the last chapter ranging from curbing the excess power at the top to creating more opportunities and investment in the bottom. It is understandable that the deep-seated inequality in our society necessitates a holistic remedy that he recommends. However, I still believe that some changes might be more urgent than others. If I were to have one-on-one with Stiglitz, I would like to ask him what reform policies he thinks should be prioritized among others. It would be interesting to hear what he believes to be the most pressing issue.
In general, Stiglitz does a magnificent job in analyzing the
inequality and market failure in the modern US economy. However, I cannot help
but feel that Stiglitz could have better organized his book. For instance,
there were quite numerous instances in which he accuses the top 1 percent of
exploiting politics but does not thoroughly explain ‘how’ they did so each
time. He does enlist various mechanisms they use in later chapters, yet these
explanations are rather scattered throughout the book. I would have preferred
if Stiglitz dedicated a chapter or two to focus mainly on describing how those
ruling the economy also influenced politics. Although such a task would have
been very difficult given the broad topic he chose to discuss, organizing the
book in this way might have helped readers better understand and adopt his
argument.
No comments:
Post a Comment